Is Marxism Still Valid in Industrial
Relations Theory?

Anam
Ullah
Correspondence:
Asm Anam Ullah
Doctoral Scholar and Academic
Macquarie University, Australia
Email: russell_adib@yahoo.com.au

Abstract
All too often, scholars are posed
with questions as to whether Marxism
has any relationships with modern
industrial relations theory. Many
say yes, many say no. However, there
is a crucial debate in the public
domain about industrial relations
theory and many try to portray it
from different analytical tools. This
short article will mediate on this
issue whether Marxism is still valid
in the current industrial relations
theory.
Key words: Marxism, Industrial
Relations Theory and Trade unions.

Introduction
"The philosophers have only
interpreted the world in various ways
but the real task is to alter it".
Karl Marx
The industrial relations (IRs) or
employment relation (ERs) theorists
have not thus far reached a certain
agreement to declare that this is
the ultimate theory of industrial
relations. Last couple of centuries
there have been many academic and
great scholars who saw industrial
relations in a different perspective.
They also tried to find the best theory
of industrial relations, but thus
far, it is most likely to see that
there is not any universal theory
of industrial relations that any potential
industrial relations student can adopt.
However, there is a significant amount
of research growing and offering different
methods of IR and ER and we can take
scholars' guideline while studying
industrial relation and employment
relations.
As an approach of Marxism in industrial
relations, a neo-Marxists interpretation
of the industrial relations or labour
process is crucial and it often conflicts
with the contemporary scholars. There
is strong debate whether Marxism is
considered as an industrial relations
theory. This short article, despite
its own limitations, the extent to
which will arrest some scholarly written
debates on these issues. Thus, theoretically
this qualitative analysis will discuss
by developing a theoretical framework
of the industrial relations theory
first, and then incorporate the scholar's
point whether Marxism is still valid
in industrial relations theory.
The Core Ideas
of Industrial Relations
The term "Industrial Relations"
(IR) has come to be established into
common use in Britain and America
during the 1920s. Initially, to some
extent, some started using IR theory
incorporating with Personal Management
(PM) and, since the 1980s, Human Resource
Management (HRM). But, interestingly,
these three have common traits in
the practical field which is based
on one single concept (management
of people) and therefore, academic
inquiries are essential in this field
(see Edwards, 2009).
Again, to avoid confusion and academic
debate, on some facets, scholars also
use "term" Employment Relations
(ER) instead of IR. Nevertheless,
some scholars try to isolate IR and
ER from a different perspective. In
saying this, again, when I went through
the scholarly written articles I strongly
found notions of IR and ER theories
and I tried to understand their basic
and fundamental differences from an
analytical observations.
Interestingly, IR, the extent to which
it covers relationships between managers
and employees is always determined
by the economic activity. This relationship
perhaps reveals a mutual understanding
between managers and employees where
economic benefits are the main agenda
of both parties. But, scholars thus
far have identified that IR theory
excludes domestic and also the self-employed
who work on their own account and
therefore they are also accountable
to maintain their own labour standards
which shows the system of self-regulation
or self-accountability.
Moreover, this concept originated
partly from the International Labour
Organization (ILO) and its European
stakeholders where Civil law is more
prominent than the Common law. Again,
according to Edward (2009), the point
is, however, when self-employed professionals
deal with customers, the extent to
which, it makes it extensively difficult
to say whether such relationship determine
the concept of "industrial relations",
but again, for understanding, potential
IR students can consider this as a
part of industrial relations when
there is a contractual agreement between
a self-employed firm and its employees
(see Edward, 2009, Eberhard, 2007;
Kaufman, 2004).
Alternatively, scholars tried to portray
the term "ER" from a different
facet. In saying this, when potential
IR or ER students try to isolate this
both from each other, to some extent,
ER theory itself focuses on: all forms
of economic activity in which certainly
all employees work under a certain
authoritative role which emerges from
the employers and therefore employees
receive wages in return for their
labour - this model represents a substantive
issue of IR system where the procedural
rule deals with conflicts between
employer and employee (see Edward,
2009; Quinlan, 2004).
Again, by the nature of the world
of work, scholars identified that
the great majority of the population
in modern times, of course, are employees
rather than employers. Some scholars
define IR theory as less effective
rather than studying all forms of
the employment relationship. But,
the debate still grows and many say
this is not to some extent a sufficient
support that contemporary observers
are trying to establish in which the
IR theory is not valid anymore, rather
scholars say it is indeed very hard
to justify the concept and implications
of IR in the current industrial studies
by grasping the narrow concept from
the economics or sociology of work
(see Eberhard, 2007; Kaufman, 2004;
Abbot, 2006).
However, whether I use the term 'employment
relations" instead of "industrial
relations", these both work on
labour regulation and scholars say
regulation comes from various sources
(see Eberhard, 2007). But there is
one common characteristic found in
scholarly written articles: employment
relations and industrial relations
deal with employer and employee and
either individually or collectively
for procedural rules or substantive
rules as these are all directly engaged
in the workplace (see Ross, 2008;
Kaufman, 2010; Chidi & Okpala,
2012).
Kaufman (2010) saw industrial relations
as the process of rulemaking for the
workplace Dunlop (1958) identified
the actors of employment or industrial
relations. Other scholars contributed
in labour regulation such as Flanders
(1965); social regulation of production
by Cox (1971); Edwards (2005) saw
the employment relationship as structured
antagonism. Social regulation of market
forces was described by Hyman (1995).
According to Bain and Clegg (1974)
cited in Chidi and Okpala (2012),
"a traditional approach to employment
and industrial relations has been
to regard it as the study of the rules
governing employment, and the ways
in which the rules are changed, interpreted
and administered".
Again, Dunlop 1958; Edward (2009);
Freeman (2007); Eberhard (2007); Kaufman
(2004); Gunningham (2008); Jentsch
(2004); Johnstone (2008); Flenders
(1965); Quinlan (2004); Poole (2013);
Kittel (1967); identified three major
parties in the IR or ER system which
are (a) state (b) employer and (c)
trade union. In modern time, there
are some crucial changes in IR or
ER theories. The following model represents
the best employment relations.
Figure 1: The employment relationship
hired from Edwards, P. (Ed.). (2009).
Industrial relations: theory and practice.
The above model represents the most
common structure of employment relations
which was invented by Dunlop in 1958.
However, the contemporary IR thinkers
are offering different models of IR
and ER than the traditional concept
or models. However, to some extent,
the major parties are identified in
labour regulation by almost every
scholar, which I have already mentioned
about the three parties in the past.
Some outsourcing and external regulation
can be taken into consideration in
order to analyse the IR and ER system
in the different contexts, but as
Dunlop identified major three actors
in his (1958) IR theory, to some extent
this is still valid, but other concepts
are simultaneously considered by the
international academics and scholars
in this area.
According to Abbot (2006, p. 187):
"Work is fundamental to the
human condition. It determines what
we do for much of our waking lives
and it preoccupies much of what we
think about. It allows us to engage
with other people and it helps us
to define our sense of identity. It
provides us with access to the material
necessities of life, as well as to
the advantages and achievements of
civilisation. Its allocation, organisation,
management and reward are therefore
of no small importance. How these
are undertaken in gainful employment
tells us much about the views and
values we hold as a society. What
levels of unemployment are deemed
tolerable, what manner of work is
undertaken and how disputes between
the two sides of industry are resolved,
for example, are all matters about
which we have opinions and which are
often shaped by the prevailing cultural
boundaries, economic circumstances
and political understandings we hold
towards our engagement with work".
Indeed, for the purpose of this discussion
above, the nature of work has tremendously
changed during the last one hundred
years or so. The technological changes
made the work of the world more challenging.
People are now working in different
ambiences and employment relations
studies are now facing more challenges
to develop an appropriate theory of
ER or IR.
However, a large number of growing
research is suggesting and focusing
on the issue of industrial conflict
and meditating on this issue to solve
all the unresolved issues, but, to
some extent, there are also substantial
amounts of scholarly written articles
which have caused confusion about
the current and past IR and ER theories.
In these processes, many scholars
portrayed the IR and ER theory from
different analytical lenses, however,
it is identified that the industrial
relations theory has done so with
less uniformity and till now scholars
are introducing different ideas of
IR and ER theories according to the
context ("budgetary/market, technological
characteristics of the work place
and work community and the locus and
distribution of power in the larger
society") (see Chidi and Okpala
2012; Bray et al., 2014).
So, grounded situation is playing
a big role over the creation of IR
and ER theories. As a potential IR
and ER researcher, I found, the extent
to which, developing countries are
suffering from various issues in labour
or Occupational Health and Safety
(OHS) mainly. Western or European
countries have different labour issues
in all aspects. So, labour issues
in Common law countries and Civil
law countries have a different situation.
However, Socialist state also has
a completely different philosophy
in regards to control labour problems
than the Common or Civil law states
(Sisson & Marginson, 2001). In
addition, industrial relations has
different approaches.
Nevertheless, again, whether it is
the Common law, Civil law or a Socialist
law, one thing can be understood from
a deeper perspective that labour is
the most crucial part of their economy,
so the state needs to learn how to
develop a better labour institutions,
thus, labour issues can be identified
easily and these problems can solved
by giving an equal effort both from
academic and professional levels (see
Vogel, 2006; Guzman & Meyer, 2010).
However, as many academic scholars
have pointed out that there are distinct
approaches in the employment relationship
and these approaches are identified
from different analytical tools and
different intellectually written documents.
As I mentioned the employment relation
studies are bringing so many paradoxes
and it is not an easy way to find
which approach is being appropriate
in which context. But, to some extent,
as a potential researcher, it is my
obligation to reveal how each of these
approaches is related to the context.
But to be very specific in this article,
as I already mentioned that my analyses
will be based on a specific issue
which is (Marxism or Radicalism) and
whether there is any connection with
the current industrial relation studies
or theories, thus my next analyses
will be focusing on this particular
issue rather than discussing the other
approaches more elaborately in this
article.
The following figure represents the
most common approaches to the employment
relationship.
Figure 2: alternative approaches
adopted from Bray et al., (2014, p.
15)
Marxist Theory
According to Chidi and Okpala (2012);
Abbot (2006); Kaufman (2004, 2010),
Marxism, however, unambiguously appeared,
more or less, to establish a general
theory of society and social change
with colossal implications for the
analysis of industrial relations within
the capitalist societies which does
not or to some extent has not any
affinities with the industrial relations
theory. Interesting indeed! In saying
so, again, scholars like Kaufman (2004)
revealed something very significant
for potential industrial relations
students; point is, however, neither
the notion of labour relations nor
the term of industrial relations,
belongs to the vocabulary of Karl
Marx (see Kaufman, 2004).
As debate grows on, more theoretically
offered an idea of such debate by
Ogunbameru (2004) cited in Chidi and
Okpala (2012), point, however, to
some extent, the application of Marxian
theory as it partly relates to industrial
relations today derives from later
Marxist scholars rather than directly
from the composition of Karl Marx
himself (see Chidi and Okpala, 2012).
Again, Kaufman (2010) pointed out
that more or less during the 1870
-1920 the industrial relations term
to some extent was originated within
a limited number of works as a response
to the worldwide "Labour Problems"
(or "Social Question") because
industrial development and industrial
society emerged at that time. Research
identifies that there was a conflict
between capitalism and socialism and
these both had revolution at that
time. Also, labour reform project
met many obstacles and objections
during that period. The world was
divided into the ideas of orthodox
classical and neoclassical economics.
According to Kaufman (2010, p. 76):
"The body of theory, largely
imported from Britain but secondarily
from France, was widely accepted,
hence establishing it as "orthodox."
The most widely accepted lesson of
orthodox economics at this time was
the principle of free trade; second
on the list was Say's Law - the contention
that a free-market system automatically
returns to an equilibrium position
of full employment. Free trade applied
first and foremost to international
exchange of goods between countries,
but the principle was extended with
only negligible qualification to domestic
and factor markets, including, most
importantly, labour markets".
Chidi and Okpala (2012) cited in Hyman
(1975, p. 12) where he defines "industrial
relations as the study of the processes
of control over work relations and
among these processes, those involving
collective worker organisation and
action are of particular concern".
Hayman known as an orthodox Marxist
has given a strong notion of industrial
relations theory - and put it this
way - Hayman asserted that this is
Dunlop and Flanders, who of them are
the giant industrial relations theorist
thus far, but again, some scholars
conceptualized the issue of industrial
relations theory which has specially
come from Dunlop (1958) and was limited
to some extent, especially finding
the actors and actor's role within
the labour or employment regulation
process. Hayman's main point, in saying
this, put it this way again, it is
almost impossible to come up with
a complete industrial relations theory
at a time rather it develops through
an on-going process and maintenance
and stability in performance in industrial
regulation is a must (Chidi &
Okpala, 2012; Hayman, 1975; Kaufman,
2004; Jentsch, 2004).
Again, Abbot (2006, p. 194) pointed
out that:
"A Marxist frame of reference
may seem redundant in view of the
break-up of the Soviet Union, the
collapse of communism in Eastern Europe
and the decline of 'radical' thinking
in the West. There are, however, a
number of studies from this school
of thought that remain influential.
This is because they are based on
vastly different assumptions about
the nature and cause of workplace
conflict, and second, because they
act as valid critiques of the previous
two frames of reference and their
associated theories. Those arguing
from a radical perspective draw principally
from the work of Karl Marx (1950,
1967, 1978), who argued that capitalist
societies were characterised by perpetual
class struggle. This struggle is caused
by inequalities in the distribution
of wealth and the skewed ownership
of the means of production. Wealth
and property ownership, he observed,
were highly concentrated in the hands
of a small number of bourgeoisie (or
capitalists), whilst the vast mass
of the proletariat (or workers) lived
in poverty and had nothing to sell
but their labour".
In saying this, once again, I need
to point Hayman's analyses in this
issue, he asserted similarly as contemporary
scholars saw the Marxist theory and
blended into different shapes.
Chidi & Okpala (2012, p, 273)
cited in Hayman (1975) in which he
asserted that:
"The Marxist perspectives
typify workplace relations as a reflection
of the incidence of societal inequalities
and the inevitable expression of this
at the work place. To sum it up, Hyman
further states that industrial relations
is all about power, interests and
conflict and that the economic, technological
and political dynamics of the broader
society inevitably shape the character
of relations among industrial relations
actors which he described as the political
economy of industrial relations. Conflict
is viewed as a disorder precursor
to change and to resolve conflict
means to change the imbalance and
inequalities in society in terms of
power and wealth. Trade unions are
viewed as employee response to capitalism".
Then, again, as a potential researcher,
to some extent, I cannot ignore saying
what other scholars identified analogously,
put this way, Marx's theory connected
with how people relate to the most
fundamental resource of all us, it
means, again, through his observation,
labour was treated as power of their
own labour. The whole, in fact, between
1844 and 1883, a period of democratic
nationalism, trade unionism and revolution
was his main theme of writing. The
labour is fundamental to Marx's theories.
Basically, Marx , for the first time
arrested a significant point in his
theory, put this way - he argued that
it is simply human nature to transform
nature, and he calls this process
of transformation "labour"
and the capacity to transform nature,
'labour power.'
However, to scholars like Kaufman
(2004), the point is, he asserted
that Marx's core institutions the
extent to which it is fundamentally
focusing on industrial relations-free
labour markets and the factory system-where
Kaufman found that the major components
of Marx's analysis of industrial capitalism,
and he was a keen observer, thus he
addressed on labour issues extensively
and mainly in trade unionism. But,
many scholars say - his main focus
was on classifying the distinct gaps
between labour and capital. Scholars
also pointed out that, he, to some
extent, albeit his ideology was based
on trade unionism, however, he could
not show how trade unions can be a
fruitful organization in terms of
obtaining the ultimate success through
the collective process in terms of
wage discriminations and other labour
issues.
But, however, the way he saw, it is
not the actual nature of trade unions
at present that we see around the
world where trade unions in many Western
and European countries are developed
as an institution. Contrarily, in
many developing countries, trade union
has not yet been treated as a supportive
force of changing the labour or OHS
conditions as they have little collective
bargaining scope and in some countries
like Cambodia, China, Bangladesh and
so on, where, to some extent, trade
union leaders are brutally killed
and tortured (see, Kaufman, 2004,
2010; Chidi & Okpala, 2012; Hayman,
1975; Abbot, 2006; Flanders, 1965;
Brown et al, 2013; Marston, 2007;
Munck, 2010: Islam & McPhail,
2011).
In saying this, many say, his main
focus on trade unions show radicalism
rather showing how they can collectively
raise their concern about the exploitation.
As we see now in many countries like
the U.K, Australia, where the labour
party represents the trade union and
trade union has been treated as one
of the crucial actors in the industrial
relations system which is absent in
the Marxist theory (see Kaufman, 2004;
Balnave et al., 2009).
Concluding remarks
But in the case of Marxism it is especially
incredible to realize that a few (only
a few now), still believe that its
promised golden age will yet arrive
as capitalism drastically grasped
the global market. Yet Marxism had
the perfect opportunity to demonstrate
its promised wonder and glory in the
Soviet and Chinese experiments in
which state-wide Marxist support was
imposed and deviating opinions banned.
What were the fruits of those experiments;
this makes another debate which is
inevitable.
Whatsoever, industrial relations system
and market system have tremendously
changed during the last one hundred
years or so, thus many believe, Marx's
theory has not yet demised indeed
as we still see huge exploitations
around the world especially where
global capital drastically took control
over the labour market. Developing
nations are suffering from inadequate
resources, thus, those developing
nations compromising with the capitalist
by offering abundant cheap labour
like Cambodia's and Bangladeshi's
garment industry where millions of
poor and rural migrated workers are
working with very low wages. Technological
changes are the major concern for
the labour at this moment as capitalists
are investing in this field. So, to
some extent, whether it is directly
related to the Marx's theory of industrial
relations, however, his labour theory
still shows huge potential for further
research in this area.
Finally, as I said, it is indeed almost
impossible to bring all the analyses
in this article as this area is quite
enormous. However, for a potential
researcher, it would be wise to consider
in order to understand Marx's theory,
whether it has any connection with
the modern form of industrial relations
theory by analysing further from his
the political economy of industrial
relations, labour process analysis,
and the French regulation school.
However, thus far, there very little
support has been identified in scholarly
written articles where Marxism has
been considered as an industrial relations
theory.
References
Abbott, K. (2006). A review of employment
relations theories and their application.
Problems and Perspectives in Management,
1(2006), 187-199.
Balnave, N., Brown, J., Maconachie,
G., & Stone, R. (2009). Employment
relations in Australia, 2nd edn, John
Wiley & Sons, Australia Ltd.
Bray, M., Waring, P., Cooper, R.,
& MacNeil, J. (2014). Employment
relations: theory and practice, 3rd
addition, McGraw-Hill, Sydney.
Brown, D., Dehejia, R., & Robertson,
R. (2013). Regulations, Monitoring,
and Working Conditions: Evidence from
Better Factories Cambodia and Better
Work Vietnam. Working paper, Tufts
University. http://users. nber. org/~
rdehejia/papers/Brown _Dehejia_Robertson_RDW.
pdf.
Chidi, C. O., & Okpala, O. P.
(2012). Theoretical Approaches to
Employment and Industrial Relations:
A Comparison of Subsisting Orthodoxies.
INTECH Open Access Publisher.
Cox, R. (1971). "Approaches to
the Futurology of Industrial Relations."
Bulletin of the
Institute of Labour Studies, Vol.
8, N0. 8, pp. 139-64.
Dunlop, J.T. (1958). Industrial Relations
Systems. New York: Holt (title now
owned by Cengage Learning)
Eberhard, A. (2007). Infrastructure
Regulation in Developing Countries:
an exploration of hybrid and transitional
models, Public-Private Infrastructure
Advisory Facility, Working paper 4.
Edwards, P. (Ed.). (2009). Industrial
relations: theory and practice. John
Wiley & Sons.
Flanders, A. (1965). Industrial Relations:
What is Wrong with the System? An
Essay on Its Theory and Future. London:
Farber & Farber.
Freeman, R. B. (2007). Labor market
institutions around the world (No.
w13242). National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Gunningham, N. (2008). Occupational
health and safety, worker participation
and the mining industry in a changing
world of work. Economic and Industrial
Democracy, Vol. 29(3), 336-361.
Guzman, A., & Meyer, T. L. (2010).
Explaining soft law. Berkeley Program
in Law & Economics.
Hyman, R. (1995). "Industrial
Relations in Theory and Practice."
European Journal of
Industrial Relations, Vol. 1, No.
1, pp. 17-46.
Hyman, R. (1975). Industrial Relations:
A Marxist Introduction. London: Macmillan.
Islam, M.A., McPhail, K. (2011). Regulating
for corporate human rights abuses:
the emergence of corporate reporting
on the ILO's human rights standards
within the global garment manufacturing
and retail industry. Critical Perspectives
on Accounting,No. 22, pp. 790-810.
Jentsch, W. M., (2004). Theoritical
approach to industrial relations,
in Kaufman, B. E., (eds), "Theoretical
perspectives on work and the employment
relationship", Cornell University
Press.
Johnstone, R. (2008). 'Harmonising
Occupational Health and Safety Regulation
in Australia: The First Review of
the National OHS Review'.
Kaufman, B. E. (2010). The theoretical
foundation of industrial relations
and its implications for labor economics
and human resource management.Industrial
& Labor Relations Review, 64(1),
74-108.
Marston, A. (2007). Labour monitoring
in Cambodia's Garment Industry: Lesson
for Africa. Realizing Rights - The
Ethical Globalization Initiative.
Marx, K. (1956). Capital. Volume 1,
Chapter 10. Progress Publishers, Moscow,
USSR.
Munck, R.P. (2010) "Globalization
and the labour movement: challenges
and responses," Global Labour
Journal: Vol. 1: Iss. 2, p. 218-232.
Ogunbameru, A. O. (2004). Organisational
Dynamics. Ibadan: Spectrum Books Ltd,
Quinlan, M. (2004). Regulatory responses
to OHS problems posed by direct-hire
temporary workers in Australia. Journal
of Occupational Health and Safety
Australia and New Zealand, Vol. 20(3),
241-254.
Rose, E.D. (2008). Employment Relations.
(3rd ed).London: Pearson Education
Ltd.
Sisson, K., & Marginson, P. (2001).
" Soft Regulation": Travesty
of the Real Thing Or New Dimension?.
ESRC" One Europe or Several?"
Programme, Sussex European Institute,
University of Sussex.
Vogel, D. (2006). The private regulation
of global corporate conduct. Center
for Responsible Business.
|